Cancer Drugs Will Become Terminal for Health Systems
Friday, 28 August, 2015
(If We Don't Talk About Value)
, ; , , and ,
from across the United States have called on charged by pharmaceutical companies for new cancer drugs. They claim drug companies, insurance companies, some patient advocacy groups and many hospitals and physicians are .
Their call is motivated by the astronomical prices charged for some new cancer drugs. And Australia is in the same boat. Earlier this year, for instance, the Pharmaceutical Benefits Scheme (PBS) for the treatment of patients with advanced melanoma. The drug is expected to cost A$150,000 per patient for each year of treatment, which is the national average annual income.
Unlike in the United States, where patients' insurance covers the costs, the Australian taxpayer subsidises . In cases where new drugs are not subsidised, they鈥檙e paid for directly by patients, or by state-funded hospitals (often after approval by drug committees). They can also be provided free or subsidised by pharmaceutical companies for 鈥渃ompassionate use鈥.
Blurred by emotion
Decisions to subsidise drugs and improve their accessibility should be based on an assessment of their value. In Australia, for instance, the examines new drugs for effectiveness, safety and value for money compared to other treatments before recommending PBS listing 鈥 or not.
But the imperative to 鈥渟ave lives鈥 or 鈥渂eat cancer鈥 鈥 particularly where there鈥檚 vigorous public, professional and industry advocacy 鈥 can be so profound that it overwhelms the requirement that medicines should be efficacious and cost-effective. This tension between emotional and economic considerations frequently challenges and compromises public decision-making about the value of drugs.
Consider the case of eribulin (Halaven), a drug for treating advanced breast cancer. The UK (NICE is the rough equivalent of PBAC although it has a broader role) considered the drug but rejected it as too expensive.
by the , a pool of public money allocated to pay for drugs not approved via the usual route. The price accepted by the fund was among the highest in Europe for the drug; the price rejected by NICE had been the lowest.
Clearly, when standards of cost-effectiveness are reduced in the name of 鈥渋mproved access鈥, prices can rise arbitrarily. In most markets, supply and demand, competition and consumer choice curtail such arbitrary fluctuations in price.
But the market for innovative cancer drugs doesn鈥檛 follow this pattern because prices can increase dramatically even in 鈥済rowing鈥 markets, without clear reasons. In 2013, for example, a group of how the price of imatinib (Gleevec) increased three-fold over a decade. This happened even though all research and development costs were accounted for in the original price, and the number of people using the drug was dramatically increasing. Heightened demand alone cannot explain such an increase.
What makes cancer drugs different
Cancer drug markets clearly behave quite differently to what we might expect. There are three key reasons for this.
First, governments are creating a 鈥減rice deregulation eco-system鈥 for cancer drugs by establishing special funds that challenge accepted standards of value, and by curtailing the ability of payers to negotiate prices. The UK government has the Cancer Drugs Fund discussed above, while US legislation limits the ability of 鈥 the US government鈥檚 health insurance program for people who are 65 and older and certain others 鈥
. Laws in the latter country effectively force the health insurer to pay for cancer drugs used for a 鈥渕edically accepted indication鈥, and prevent it from considering related cancer drugs as interchangeable.
In other words, US Medicare cannot make the call about whether the drug is worth its asking price, or negotiate prices based on cheaper available alternatives. The fact that the US pays the most for many drugs 鈥 including many cancer drugs 鈥 should therefore be no surprise. And if other countries are paying high prices for drugs, it makes it easier to justify these high prices elsewhere.
Second, there鈥檚 a lack of significant competition for many new cancer drugs. In an attempt to understand why South Korea paid so much less for drugs used to treat chronic myeloid leukemia 鈥 in some instances less than 20% of the US price 鈥 the noted the country had its own locally discovered drug for treating this disease. The price of competing products appeared to be based on this local drug鈥檚 price.
The lack of competition in the cancer drugs market is exacerbated by the rise of new 鈥溾, which are more difficult to replicate than small-molecule drugs, and aimed at extending the patent lives of existing products, thwarting generic competition.
Finally, markets in health care, including for high-cost cancer drugs, are powerfully influenced by existential and moral considerations 鈥 specifically fear of death and disability, and desire for greater quantity and quality of life. Cancer patients, their families and the oncologists who care for them are often willing to try drugs in the hope they will work, regardless of the price or prospect of benefit, which is frequently quite limited in the case of new, expensive cancer therapies. And as long as there are people willing to pay high prices or, as is usually the case, to demand subsidised access to cancer drugs, there鈥檚 no reason for the industry to reduce its prices.
Hope, fear and desperation, along with the unique characteristics of the cancer drug market, create a 鈥減erfect storm鈥 that continues to drive up prices for cancer drugs. Unless we regain sight of the need to use regulatory incentives to reward only genuine innovation, and ensure that we receive sufficient value for the money we spend on new medicines, this upward trend for cancer drug prices is set to continue.
The call by the for patients to demand reductions in the price of the new drugs may be too much of an ask as these people have more to lose in this debate. It may also be too narrowly focused as it鈥檚 not just cancer patients but all of us who should demand the drugs we need at a price that our publicly funded health systems can afford.
CORRECTION: This article has been amended to reflect the fact that the PBS lists subsidised drugs, not the Therapeutic Goods Administration it said originally.

is Postdoctoral Research Associate, Centre for Values, Ethics and the Law in Medicine at .
is Associate Professor in Bioethics & Director, Centre for Values and Ethics and the Law in Medicine at .
is Senior Research Fellow, Bioethics at .
This article was originally published on .
Read the
Perioperative nurses take on surgical escape room
Nursing staff at Calvary Adelaide 黑料吃瓜群网 have taken part in a new perioperative escape room...
Report: ACN calls for greater nurse UCC program recognition
In the wake of an interim evaluation report of Medicare Urgent Care Clinics, the Australian...
How and why safety and quality standards are evolving
After 30 years in the healthcare sector, Dr Karen Luxford has seen many changes to safety and...